Tag: Education

  • Wichita School Bond Issue Opponents: Driving What? And How?

    In his Sunday Wichita Eagle column, Mark McCormick complains that the Wichita school bond issue opponents are a) cynical, b) short-sighted, c) myopic, d) forces pulling us backwards, e) frightening voters, f) spending too much at Starbucks, g) only saying “no,” h) hiding their true agenda to replace public schools with vouchers, i) not honest advocates, j) meaning the school district no good, and k) meaning the students no good.

    I don’t know if this is a complete list. Read the column at Naysayers shouldn’t drive school bond debate and see for yourself.

    Like his colleague Bob Lutz, some people don’t see how much they already have. Lutz complained that because some athletic facilities are being considered for removal from the bond issue plan, he might change his mind and vote against the bond, following the lead of Wichita school board member Jeff Davis. Never mind how much is still in the plan, as mentioned here: Will Bob Lutz Follow Jeff Davis on the Wichita School Bond Issue?

    In this case, Mr. McCormick may not be aware that for the coming school year, it’s possible that per-student spending will exceed $13,000. Or, he may not be aware that each resident of USD 259 is taxed, on average, $1,749 each year to pay for Wichita school spending. The other night I was visiting friends, a family of four. Their tax burden is $6,996 each year to pay for Wichita public school spending. The fact that they suffer this burden while also working to pay private school tuition for their two children must mean nothing to Mr. McCormick. He thinks they should pay more.

    When it’s “for the kids” the sacrifices people make are never enough to satisfy some people.

    But what’s most curious about this column is that I get the sense that Mr. McCormick thinks bond issue opponents aren’t playing fair. May I remind him that neither of the opposition groups has a staff of paid professional employees working to develop plans and educate the public.

    We don’t have a union with several thousand members highly motivated to pass this bond issue for personal reasons.

    We don’t have tens of thousands of parents on our side, many eager to pay just a little more in taxes so that their children reap big benefits.

    We don’t have a prominent architecture firm working on a volunteer basis to promote the bond issue, hoping for a multi-million dollar payoff after its passage.

    We don’t have a column in the state’s largest newspaper.

    So, Mr. McCormick, just how is it that the naysayers are driving this issue?

  • Kansas School Board Candidate Forum, June 30, 2008

    I attended a forum on June 30, 2008, for candidates for two district seats on the Kansas State Board of Education. The event was held at Allison Middle School in Wichita and moderated by Randy Brown.

    Candidates attending were Walt Chappell, David Dennis, Dennis Hedke, Charles Wiggins, and Paul Casanova. Marty Marshall did not attend.

    Perhaps the biggest surprise to me is there is actually some difference on the issues between these candidates. Merit pay is such an issue. Casanova and Hedke are in favor of merit pay; Wiggins believes it has merit but would be difficult to implement; and Dennis and Chappell are opposed — strongly, in my judgment — to merit pay.

    There is also disagreement about consolidation of school districts. Chappell has the most ambitious plan, calling to reduce the number of school districts from the current 298 to 40, with each district having at least 10,000 students. He doesn’t want to close any schools, just consolidate the districts. He believes this will save $350 million per year. Those savings would not be returned to the taxpayers. Instead, they would be spent on other things in the public schools.

    All candidates agree that our public schools are underfunded.

    All agree either that the federal No Child Left Behind legislation is flawed or is not working as intended.

    All believe that teachers need to be paid more. Some mentioned an easier path to teacher certification for those people who are interested in teaching but don’t have a degree in education.

    There were a few notable remarks. Chappell believes in transparency, something that is in short supply in the Wichita public school district. Casanova said he’d do a good job on the board because “my kids” are in the public schools and that is a highly motivating factor. This reveals how the public schools are simply another special interest group.

    Wiggins made a very curious remark, saying several times that local school districts “own their own business.” This analogy or comparison is false. What type of business has a government-mandated monopoly on the use of public funds for education, those funds raised by the coercive force of government?

    My questions for the candidates, submitted in writing, were these (as best as I can remember): “What will you do to help Kansas families who, for whatever reason, decide they can’t use product the public schools produce, but can’t afford private or parochial school tuition?” Also “In Minneapolis, students can attend schools in any district as long as there are open seats. Would you support this in Kansas?” The moderator chose not to submit these questions to the candidates.

  • Wichita School Bond Issue: Surrounding Districts Are Growing and Building New Facilities

    Supporters of the proposed bond issue for USD 259, the Wichita, Kansas public school district, say that Wichita schoolchildren deserve the same nice and new facilities that many of the surrounding suburban districts have been building. Typical is an editorial in The Wichita Eagle on February 10, 2008, stating “The [Wichita school] district officials kept returning to a bottom line: Don’t our kids deserve school opportunities comparable to those in Maize or Goddard or Andover?”

    Leaving aside the question of what people deserve, but noting that the only way the Wichita school district can give kids what they deserve is by taking from someone else, there is a reason why suburban districts have new facilities: their enrollments, mostly, are growing. The Wichita school district enrollment is not growing, or growing very slowly.

    So as the suburban districts experience growth in their enrollments, they build schools. By necessity, these schools are new. They are shiny. They have modern facilities.

    One thing Kansas might consider is implementing open enrollment. This is the case in Minneapolis. As reported in The Wall Street Journal in Black Flight: The exodus to charter schools, “In 1990 Minnesota allowed students to cross district boundaries to enroll in any district with open seats. Two years later in St. Paul, the country’s first charter school opened its doors. (Charter schools are started by parents, teachers or community groups. They operate free from burdensome regulations, but are publicly funded and accountable.) Today, this tradition of choice is providing a ticket out for kids in the gritty, mostly black neighborhoods of north and south-central Minneapolis.”

    This article, well worth reading, explains what has been observed in school choice programs throughout the country: it is poor and minority families that benefit most from school choice programs, whatever their form. “Conventional wisdom holds that middle-class parents take an interest in their children’s education, while low-income and minority parents lack the drive and savvy necessary. The black exodus here demonstrates that, when the walls are torn down, poor, black parents will do what it takes to find the best schools for their kids.”

    In Wichita and Kansas, however, politicians, public education bureaucrats, and special interest groups like the teachers union show by their actions that they believe school choice is not a good idea for poor families. Middle-class and wealthy families, however, can exercise a form of school choice by moving to the suburban districts. Poor families generally don’t have that option.

    The following table and chart contain figures I gathered that compare the growth rates of Wichita and some surrounding suburban districts. Note that since about 2001, the rate of growth for the Wichita school district is somewhere near zero, while for others the average rate is two to three percent. This is a significant difference. Considering only the Maize, Goddard, and Andover districts — the school districts mentioned by the Wichita district officials — the difference is even greater.

  • Complacency is Not an Option: Kansas Needs to Drop its Dropout Rate

    From our friends at the The Flint Hills Center for Public Policy.

    Complacency is Not an Option: Kansas Needs to Drop its Dropout Rate
    Report compares dropout rates for the 20 largest districts in Kansas

    (WICHITA) – Is a high school graduation rate of 39 percent acceptable? That was the record of USD 457 Garden City and USD 501 Topeka, according to a report issued by the Flint Hills Center for Public Policy. USD 500 Kansas City did only slightly better, with a 49 percent rate.

    “Colin Powell recently called the number of students who drop out of school every year a ‘catastrophe,’” says John R. LaPlante, Education Policy Fellow at the Wichita-based think tank. “Kansas must take make some institutional changes to address its own dropout catastrophe.”

    Using the same data employed by Powell’s group in its recent report, “Cities in Crisis,” the Flint Hills Center looked at the 20 largest districts in the state, which together enroll over half of all public school students in the state. You can read the Kansas-specific report, Complacency is Not an Option: Kansas Needs to Drop its Dropout Rate, at www.flinthills.org.

    “If you compare the graduation rates from Gen. Powell’s group with the numbers from the Kansas Report Card,” says LaPlante, “you’ll find that the Report Card numbers tend to be higher. In 16 of the 20 districts, the graduation rates are higher on the Report Card by an average of 16 percentage points. The performance of schools may be worse than we thought.”

    A few districts did very well, with USD 233 Olathe, USD 266 Maize and USD 497 Lawrence graduating over 90 percent of their students in four years. But in the state’s largest district, USD 259 Wichita, only 60 percent of students graduated on time.

    Flint Hills Center for Public Policy • 250 N. Water, Suite 216 • Wichita, KS 67202-1215 • (316) 634-0218

  • Wichita School District Economic Impact

    In February 2008, Janet Harrah of the Center for Economic Development and Business Research at Wichita State University produced a report titled “Wichita Public Schools: Impact Analysis Operations Impact, Bond Impact and Success Measures.” This report painted a glowing picture of the USD 259 (Wichita, Kansas public school district) bond issue in 2000. The district uses it to promote the success of the 2000 issue, and to promote the proposed bond issue that may be voted on sometime in 2008. The study may be viewed at the CEDBR website here.

    The author of the study told me that the Wichita school district paid $1,500 for this study. Usually, research such as this that is purchased by the customer is treated as just that: something bought because it suits the customer’s needs. Since the customer controls what is done with the product, it is certain that if this study had produced a result that didn’t show a fantastically positive benefit for Wichita school district spending, the school board would not have released it to the public. But as we shall see, the way this study is structured guarantees a positive result. Also, the price of $1,500 is astonishingly low for a study of some 28 pages with three authors.

    Perhaps the primary problem with this study is that it treats the cost of the bond issue as though it doesn’t exist. The study presents evidence of the benefits of school district spending, but mentions only in passing school district taxation:

    An opportunity cost exists for the use of public funds for education. If public funds were not used to provide public education, they would be available for alternative use. Estimating the potential economic impact of alternative uses of these opportunity costs was beyond the scope of this analysis. (Page 6)

    It is the lack of analysis of these “alternative uses” that is most important. Actually, not much analysis is required. All that is needed is to recognize that when money is paid to the Wichita public schools, that money is not available for other spending. It means that when a construction worker is hired to build a Wichita school, that construction worker isn’t working on something else in Wichita. It cannot be any other way. As Henry Hazlitt explained in his classic work Economics in One Lesson:

    Therefore for every public job created by the bridge project a private job has been destroyed somewhere else. We can see the men employed on the bridge. We can watch them at work. The employment argument of the government spenders becomes vivid, and probably for most people convincing. But there are other things that we do not see, because, alas, they have never been permitted to come into existence. They are the jobs destroyed by the $1,000,000 taken from the taxpayers. All that has happened, at best, is that there has been a diversion of jobs because of the project.

    The study also uses the technique of the “multiplier,” which is to say that spending by the school district causes other spending to happen, and other jobs are therefore created. But the construction worker, whether working on a school building or a shopping mall, is paid the same and spends his wages in the same way. The multiplier effect is the same.

    This study also analyzes the impact of the bond issue (and ongoing operations) on local governments such as the City of Wichita and Sedgwick County. From page 6: “These measures view the taxing entities’ expenditures as a public investment. Public benefits are measured by tax collections. If public benefits exceed public costs then the rate of return is greater than 100 percent and the benefit-cost ratio is greater than 1.”

    These rates of return can be fantastic. For Wichita and Sedgwick County, their rate of return for the 2000 bond issue is over 1,000%! By way of explanation the study states: “These ROI percentages for the city and county are relatively high since these jurisdictions derive significant benefits from increased sales tax collections as a result of the District’s payroll, while incurring very few costs.”

    The problems with this analysis are these: First, the taxing entities’ investment is raised by taxing their residents. Second, the public benefits, as explained above, are the taxes that the government collects. It is as though we tax ourselves so that we can pay even more taxes, all this to feed the machinery of government. And if you believe in limited government and personal liberty, it is not a benefit to pay more taxes.

    While it is true that the City of Wichita derives benefits from Wichita school district spending, the city’s benefits are funded by taxes paid to the school district. It is only by considering these local governmental entities to be separate from each other that this fantastic rate of return on “investment” is possible. If the total cost of government is considered, the picture is different.

    These defects and omissions — not realizing that tax funds could be spent elsewhere if not sent to government, not realizing that benefits that government receives are the taxes that people pay, and separating government into compartments that play off each other to create artificial returns — need to recognized as we read this report.

  • Wichita Public Schools as a Public Good

    An audio recording of this article may be heard here.

    Supporters of the proposed bond issue for USD 259, the Wichita, Kansas public school district, portray Wichita’s public schools as a “public good.” Therefore, the entire community should pay for — and be happy to pay for — the ongoing operations of the schools, and should be willing to invest in a large bond issue to pay for capital improvements and new facilities.

    But is public education a public good?

    Economists tell us that one characteristic of a public good is that people can’t be excluded from consuming it. This is the case with national defense. No one can choose not to benefit from it. Schools are different, though. It is possible to exclude people from schools simply by locking the doors. Businesses of all types do this. In fact, USD 259 chooses to deny service to about 0.5% of its students each year (average expulsion rate for the last 11 years).

    Another characteristic of a public good is non-rivalrous consumption, meaning that consumption by one person doesn’t diminish another’s ability to consume. Broadcast radio and television are such goods. But public education is not this type of good. Overcrowding is given as one of the reasons for this bond issue, and education bureaucrats continuously clamor for smaller class sizes. So overcrowding must — at least according to public school administrators — reduce the quality of the education experience. Consumption, therefore, is rivalrous, and public education fails this test as a public good.

    These two characteristics are the traditional definitions of a public good, and public education fails both tests. But today a different, murkier, definition is often applied. I quote at length from Is High School Football a Public Good? by Jim Fedako, published at the Ludwig von Mises Institute. While this article speaks of football, we may remember that athletics are a large portion of the proposed bond issue for the Wichita public schools. His argument also applies to most aspects of the public schools.

    But no one really applies the technical definition to derive public goods. … Instead, the collectivist definition — the vacuous, yet now standard, definition — applies the general welfare argument to elevate football from a private activity to that of a public good. The argument goes something along these lines: football is beneficial because it prepares boys for adulthood, keeps them off the streets after school, and provides them with a place where they can excel.

    The public goods argument as currently stated says that the benefits that accrue to the child also accrue to society in general. In this collectivist view, raising children is the role of society since society benefits when it’s done right — a better work force — and suffers when it’s done wrong — more crime and criminals.

    But this argument can be applied to almost any expenditure that parents make while raising their children. Better to be jumping on ice or practicing a roundhouse kick than to be out loitering on street corners. Why limit the concept of public goods to football, basketball, baseball, softball, etc? Based on recent history, it is only a matter of time before public goods subsume more activities, with the costs spread over the community in the form of increased taxes: the complete socialism of parenting.

    The problem with the concept of public goods is that it misdirects the debate. In modern society, every action I take has a perceived positive or a perceived negative external effect on other members of society, and most of the time there are perceived positive and negative external effects occurring simultaneously. When I mow my lawn, one neighbor perceives the noise as a negative — reducing calm and tranquility — while another neighbor perceives my well-kept lawn as a benefit — invoking calm and tranquility.

    I use the qualifier “perceive” because the whole public goods argument for coerced funding of football teams is based on the perception of the observer. The parents of the football player, the player himself, as well as local high school football fans, perceive the team and games as a positive for the community. Some say that it benefits the kids, while others say it strengthens the community. Both views see tax-funded sports, football in particular, as a winner for the community.

    Yet the parent struggling to make ends meet each month, the retiree living on an inflation-robbed pension, the lover of freedom, etc., see their ever-increasing tax bill as a negative. For the parent, a child’s dental appointment goes wanting for the sake of the football team; for the retiree, the higher tax bill comes at the cost of a colder house in the winter; for lovers of freedom, additional money lifted from their wallets is another slap in the face by collectivists.

  • Let’s Spend on Wichita School Facilities, But Not Maintain Them?

    A writer in The Wichita Eagle (May 21, 2008) makes the case that since one of the persons opposed to the proposed USD 259 (Wichita public school district) bond issue in 2008 hasn’t been in a Wichita public school for many years, he isn’t as credible as he could be. If he would take a tour of the schools, he would better understand the magnitude of the problem.

    As the person who is the subject of this letter, I can say that I don’t agree with the premise of this writer. That’s because I agree that some school buildings and facilities are in poor condition.

    What’s really puzzling about the letter is this: “I have absolutely no faith that the school board will properly maintain any new sports facilities should the bond issue pass.” So this letter writer wants us to spend many millions on sports facilities and upgrades, but has no faith they will be properly cared for. Does this make any sense?

  • Everything you love you owe to capitalism

    This is an excellent article by Llewellyn H. Rockwell, Jr., president of the Ludwig von Mises Institute. An excerpt:

    I’m convinced that Mises was right: the most important step economists or economic institutions can take is in the direction of public education in economic logic.

    There is another important factor here. The state thrives on an economically ignorant public. This is the only way it can get away with blaming inflation or recession on consumers, or claiming that the government’s fiscal problems are due to our paying too little in taxes. It is economic ignorance that permits the regulatory agencies to claim that they are protecting us as versus denying us choice. It is only by keeping us all in the dark that it can continue to start war after war — violating rights abroad and smashing liberties at home — in the name of spreading freedom.

    There is only one force that can put an end to the successes of the state, and that is an economically and morally informed public. Otherwise, the state can continue to spread its malicious and destructive policies.

    The full article is here: Everything You Love You Owe to Capitalism.

  • Focus on class size in Wichita leads to misspent resources

    A popular measure proposed to produce better educational outcomes in public schools today is to reduce class size. The Wichita, Kansas public school district is currently proposing a bond issue with a partial goal of reducing class size. At least some of the recently-mandated increase in school spending in Kansas was used to reduce class size.

    It seems that smaller class sizes should be great for students. Research, however, doesn’t always verify this assumption. The Harvard economist Caroline Hoxby, now at Stanford, has stated this about her research into class size:

    I have a study in which I examined every change in class size at every elementary school in Connecticut over a 20-year period. In schools, class size varies from year to year because enrollment varies. Therefore, with 20 years and 800-some schools, there is a tremendous amount of variation in class size to examine.

    I found there was no effect of class size on achievement at all, even when children were in small classes for all six years of elementary school.

    There is, however, one study that shows increased student performance with smaller class sizes: the Tennessee STAR experiment. It is probably the study cited most often by education bureaucrats, so learning a little about it is useful. In this experiment, students were assigned to either a regular class with about 24 students, a class of the same size but with a teacher’s aide to assist the teacher, or a smaller class of about 15 students.

    Jay Greene has written about the problems with the STAR experiment. The first problem he finds is that “students were not tested when they entered the program. Such point-of-entry tests would establish a baseline for each student’s performance as it stood before the experiment began. Without this baseline measurement, we cannot confirm that the STAR project’s random assignment method was successfully carried out.”

    Second: “[there is] an anomaly in the research findings: the improvement in test scores was a one-time benefit. … This is an unusual and unexpected finding, because if smaller classes really do improve student performance we would generally expect to see these benefits accrue over time.”

    The STAR program produced a one-time improvement in tests scores that are the equivalent of a student in the 50th percentile moving to about the 58th percentile. Greene says this increase “may not amount to an educational revolution, but it is not trivial.”

    One interesting aspect of the STAR program is that participants, particularly the teachers, knew they were part of an experiment. Caroline Hoxby describes the implications of this:

    More importantly, in the Tennessee STAR experiment, everyone involved knew that if the class-size reduction didn’t affect achievement, the experimental classes would return to their normal size and a general class-size reduction would not be funded by the legislature. In other words, principals and teachers had strong incentives to make the reduction work. Unfortunately, class-size reductions are never accompanied by such incentives when they are enacted as a policy.

    Education bureaucrats and teachers often claim that schools are not like a business or other areas of human endeavor, so incentives don’t work. Education, they say, is somehow different. But it appears in the STAR program that teachers had a powerful incentive to make the small class sizes work, and they responded to that.

    Reducing class size is a very expensive measure to implement. The STAR program reduced class sizes by a large amount: from 24 to 15 students, a reduction of 38%. Many more teachers and classrooms are needed to implement reductions of this scope, and that’s why it is so expensive.

    That leads to an aspect of the problem that’s not often mentioned. Right now Wichita has a teacher shortage. The district can’t hire and retain enough teachers. Implementing class size reduction programs requires more teachers and makes the shortage even more acute.

    Compounding this problem is that research shows that teacher quality is a very important factor in the success of students. If we can assume that the most highly-qualified teachers are hired first, then increasing the number of classrooms means hiring more less-qualified teachers. So some students will be taught by poor teachers, and since class sizes are smaller, fewer students will be in the classrooms led by good teachers.

    There is no doubt that teachers and the education establishment like smaller class sizes. Smaller classes mean an easier workload for teachers, larger budgets for school district administrators and politicians, and more teachers union members paying dues. The local board of education can tell parents that they have “saved the children” and the parents will believe them. The research, however, is not settled on the benefits of smaller class sizes, and the unintended consequence of more students being taught by less-qualified teachers is a large negative effect.